Two recent reports highlight the benefits of using “reverse auctions”. In a reverse auction, the buyer specifies a quantity to be purchased, and sellers bid to provide a portion of that quantity. An article in Utility Dive summarizes some of the experiences with renewable market auctions. A separate report in the Review of Environmental Economics and Policy goes further to lay out five guidelines:
- Encourage a Large Number of Auction Participants
- Limit the Amount of Auctioned Capacity
- Leverage Policy Frameworks and Market Structures
- Earmark a Portion of Auctioned Capacity for Less-mature Technologies
- Balance Penalizing Delivery Failures and Fostering Competition
This policy prescription requires well-informed policy makers balancing different factors–not a task that is well suited to a state legislature. How to develop such a coherent policy can done in two ways. The first is to let the a state commission work through a proceeding to set an overall target and structure. But perhaps a more fruitful approach would be to let local utilities, such as California’s community choice aggregators (CCAs) to set up individual auctions, maybe even setting their own storage targets and then experimenting with different approaches.
California has repeatedly made errors by overly relying on centralized market structures that overcommit or mismatch resource acquisition. This arises because a mistake by a single central buyer is multiplied across all load while a mistake by one buyer within a decentralized market is largely isolated to the load of that one buyer. Without perfect foresight and a distinct lack of mechanisms to appropriately share risk between buyers and sellers, we should be designing an electricity market that mitigates risks to consumers rather than trying to achieve a mythological “optimal” result.
Pingback: A misguided perspective on California’s rooftop solar policy | Economics Outside the Cube